Search This Blog

Tuesday, March 4, 2014

Economics for Cheerleaders

With the Super Bowl finished (yeah Seahawks!) media attention has switched from the teams and players to the cheerleaders. A couple of recent articles caught our attention and, of course, we just couldn’t resist the temptation to comment. 

ABC News is reporting that a Cincinnati Bengal Cheerleader is suing the team over what she claims is a $2.85 per hour wage. The NY Daily News, meanwhile, published an article about the Oakland Raiderettes suing their team for similar reasons. While we don’t claim to know a lot about cheerleading, we do know a lot about economics and the way markets work. Given that, we feel it necessary to warn the cheerleaders that brought these suits to beware of the law of unintended consequences.

We checked a few of the NFL websites and found that the pay wasn’t all that great, and most had a very strict contract. These are not working conditions that we would be willing to accept, but then, we didn’t apply. A cheerleading squad consists of 30 very fit women, each of whom successfully made it through the audition process and accepted the terms of their contracts. The teams that we looked at admit that these are part-time jobs. No one should expect to make a decent living as a part-time cheerleader. 

That, in itself, suggest that there is some other non-pecuniary benefit to being an NFL cheerleader. Opportunities listed on team websites include modeling, exposure, networking, personal appearances and promotions. Indications are that between 200 and 1000 applicants pay $25 each to apply to be cheerleaders each year. They then attend training seminars just for the privilege of trying out. In economic parlance, there is an excess supply of cheerleaders. Most teams have at least 6 applicants for each available spot. 

If the $2.85/hr. figure claimed in the Bengals lawsuit is accurate, the equilibrium wage rate for cheerleaders is likely close to zero. The exposure, it appears, is sufficient compensation for the duties that they perform. 

What happens if the Raiderette and Ben-Gals are successful in their lawsuits and the NFL is forced to increase he pay of cheerleaders? Unfortunately for the existing cheerleaders, they may lose their jobs. Supply curves are upward sloping. An increase in the wage rate increases the number of people that are willing to work. If there are 200 people applying to be cheerleaders when the rate is a purported $2.85/hr., how many will apply at $7.85, the minimum wage in Ohio? Certainly more than 200. As the wage rate rises, it becomes sensible for professional dancers to audition. Not only does the number of applicants rise, but so too does the quality of the applicant. 

If, and when, the wage rate approaches the equilibrium level, the number of applicants will decrease and the quality of the applicant decreases. This fundamental rule of labour markets applies not only to NFL cheerleaders, but to bank presidents as well.

Friday, February 14, 2014

The Pricing of Wine and Beer

People in Canada are always whining about the price of beer. This is especially true once they compare prices in the U.S., and the vast majority of Canadians live within 200km of the border. The most recent case we’ve found is from a Globe and Mail article dated Dec 20, 2013. 

This provides us with an excellent opportunity to explain how retail prices are determined when firms are not perfectly competitive. The formula: P=MC/(1+1/ɛ) isn’t particularly hard to compute from the profit maximizing rule, but it is sufficiently difficult that it can’t be done with a calculator. Trust us (because it requires calculus) that it is the profit maximizing equation. P is the retail price, MC is the marginal cost of production and ɛ (a negative number) is the price elasticity of demand. It should be apparent that the price of a good rises as its cost of production rises. What is not so obvious is that as ɛ falls in absolute value, P rises. 

The elasticity of demand, ɛ, measures the responsiveness of consumer to changes in price. It is calculated as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price. Since people buy less of most things when price goes up, the elasticity is always negative. The more consumers react to price changes, the larger the elasticity number becomes (in absolute value – a bigger negative number). 

When consumers react strongly to price changes, we call the demand “elastic”. When they don’t respond the term is “inelastic”. The demand for a good will tend to be elastic if there are plenty of substitutes available, if the good is not a necessity, if the price is large relative to income, or if consumers have time to react. 

So, back to beer. The Globe news article is looking at the monopoly retailer of beer in Ontario: The Beer Store. There aren’t many good substitutes for beer, and there are no substitutes when it comes to purchasing beer in Ontario. The demand for beer in Ontario is likely to be relatively inelastic. Compare that to most places in the U.S. where beer can be purchased at Walmart, 7-Eleven and the local gas station. More places to buy beer means higher elasticity and lower retail prices. The price difference between Ontario and Quebec, where beer is available in convenience stores and grocery stores is 27%. It is safe to assume that the production costs are the same in the two provinces, so the price difference is caused by differences in elasticity. It shouldn’t be a surprise that the Beer Store rejects this claim and blames the differences on taxes.  

The major beer brands; Canadian, Kokanee, Blue, all have similar tastes (at least after the first couple). Craft beers, on the other hand, have very different flavours but their price is still limited by the availability of the major brands. Wine, on the other hand, is not easily substituted. A Merlot is not a substitute for a Riesling. A Beaujolais is not a Burgundy. In an article from Yahoo! Travel dated Sep 24, 2013, the author takes us through all kinds of reasons why wine is so expensive. The one reason that they miss is because restaurants can mark it up that much. A consumer that walks into a wine store and doesn’t like the price can choose not to purchase the wine and shop at a different location. A consumer in a restaurant cannot say to a waiter “excuse me while I go next door to the wine store and get a bottle for 40% of what you’re charging”. Once a consumer has entered a restaurant the demand for wine has become very inelastic and, because of that, the price can go up.

The demand for beer and wine tend to be relatively inelastic and elasticity falls as competition falls. That’s why we pay so much for beer and wine in Canada. 

(It’s also why red roses were so expensive today – Feb 14 – but we’ll save that one for next year)

Saturday, January 11, 2014

On Coffee and Climate Change


Whether one accepts or rejects the hypothesis of anthropogenic climate change, evidences does suggest that our planet is going through yet another warming cycle.

Climatologists warn of dire consequences; global food shortages, flooding and other apocalyptic events. Such is the case of a LiveScience article, reposted on Yahoo News, that predicts that I may now be directly affected. It turns out that the coffee crop in Costa Rica is suffering from the higher temperatures.

Coffee is my life blood and I would have to take the climatologists seriously if I hadn’t been trained to observe and interpret human behavior. Economists, you see, study what people actually do, not what they should do, or what we would like them to do.

For example, climatologists warn that the polar ice caps will melt and result in increased ocean levels. One estimate I found suggests that the rise could be as much as 2 meters (6.5 ft) by the year 2100 (National Geographic). That’s about 91 mm per year (0.9 in).

Spanish Banks, Vancouver BC
Spanish Banks, a beautiful beach near the University of British Columbia, regularly has tide changes of 3.6 m (12 ft.) in a 7 hour period. That means that the water can move out by 400 meters (1/4 mile) at low tide. In the summer, families can be seen playing near the water’s edge at low tide. Children build sand castles in the wet sand.

When the tide comes in, the water level rises by a half meter (20 inches) every hour. Surprisingly, no one ever drowns. Even the children eventually realize that their fortresses are doomed and move to higher ground. Observation of human behavior suggests that, as the oceans rise, some people will build dykes to protect the property, and eventually, all will move to higher ground. This is not going to be a costless exercise, but it will happen.

The same basic human behavior will determine the price of my coffee. It may be that Peter Lehrer, author of the LiveScience article, loses his coffee plantation as temperatures rise but economics suggests that coffee prices won’t rise. As the article states, land that is higher up on the mountain and currently too cold for coffee, may become farmable. Enterprising coffee growers, reacting to price changes will plant coffee at higher altitudes. As the planet warms, it will be possible to grow coffee further from the equator, and the market mechanism suggests that people will plant there as well.

Mr. Lehrer will be incurring costs from global warming disproportionately when compared to others on the planet, but that is a topic for another blog.

Climate change will cause changes in where and how we live. The transition is going to be expensive and is going to happen when is it no longer prudent to maintain the status quo. I, for one, am going to buy some ocean front property … in Houston.

 

Monday, January 6, 2014

Why We Can’t Predict Interest Rates

An article in the Financial Post has impugned me honour and the honour of other fine economists (thanks Capt. Barbossa for the verbiage).The basis of the negative press has to do with the inability to accurately predict future interest rates. I thought, therefore, that I would take this opportunity to defend my colleagues and explain why forecasting some economic variables is so difficult. In particular, I want to look at interest rates.
First, let’s be clear that there are several different interest rates. The money market rate is the rate charged on overnight loans between financial institutions. This is the rate that the Bank of Canada uses as its policy instrument. As of Jan 2, 2014, this rate was 1%. The Bank uses this interest rate to influence economic activity and the inflation rate.
The bank rate is the interest rate the central bank charges for overnight loans to major financial institutions. The bank rate is always 25 basis points above the target overnight rate. (1 basis point = 1/100th of 1%) When the target rate is 1%, the bank rate is 1.25%.
The prime rate is the interest rate that banks charge their best customers for short term loans. Since our banks can borrow as much money as they want from the Bank of Canada, the prime rate is closely linked to the bank rate.
The long term bond rate is the rate received for lending to government and corporations. Bond rates differ due to credit worthiness and by the length of the loan (maturity). Generally, the longer the maturity, the higher the interest rate will be. It is this interest rate that influences private business investment and the residential mortgage market.
Long term interest rates are determined by the demand and supply of loanable funds, or equivalently, the demand and supply of bonds. Central banks don’t have direct control on these rates but they can influence through open market sales and purchases of bonds with different maturities. This is what the US Fed is doing with its quantitative easing program.
To accurately predict short term interest rates we look to the Bank of Canada’s objectives and their policy tools. The Bank’s objective is to keep the inflation rate, as measured by the change in the core CPI, at 2% per year. They have an ‘operational guide’ of 2% plus or minus 1%. That is, they want to keep the inflation rate between 1% and 3% per year.
When economic activity; consumer spending, construction, exports etc. decreases, unemployment tends to rise and the inflation rate tends to fall. In response to this, the Bank lowers the target rate to encourage investment spending. When the economy expands too rapidly, the inflation rate rises, and the Bank raises the target rate to down the rate of expansion.
When will inflation rates rise? Not an easy question to answer. In the last several years the potential output of the economy has been growing faster than actual spending. Inflation increases when the economy gets close to capacity. A core inflation rate of 1.1% indicates that the Canadian economy is not operating at close to capacity. The US Bureau of Labor Statistics reports US inflation at 1.7% indicating that our biggest trading partner is also operating below capacity. Inflation.eu reports inflation rates of 2.09% in Great Britain, 1.34% in Germany, 0.68% in France, 0.23% in Spain and 0.66% in Italy. With little inflationary pressure in any of our other major trading partners, interest rates are not likely to increase there either.

So, when will interest rates rise? Not anytime soon!