Search This Blog

Tuesday, May 28, 2013

The Faucet is Leaking … Call the Electrician!


In 1692 when the Pilgrims left London bound for Halifax aboard the NiƱa, the Pinta and the Santa Maria, they brought with them 100 head of dairy cattle. By 1776, when Canada separated from England to become the 51st state, the dairy cattle roamed wild over most of the prairies.
There is a very good reason that economists don’t comment on history – it is not our field of expertise.
One must wonder, then, how accurate an op-ed piece that appeared in the Vancouver Province could be. The piece was a critique of a Fraser Institute study on milk marketing boards. It was, however, written by a historian.
In his effort to critique, our historian has made two errors that are common to any first year student. The first is the difference between ‘cost’ and ‘price’. The second is the difference between ‘demand’ and ‘quantity demanded’.
‘Cost’ refers to the market value of all of the inputs used in the production of a product. ‘Price’ is how much a consumer pays for the product, and is based on the consumer’s perceived value. When price exceeds cost, the producer earns a profit. Price can be determined either through a market system or by direct government control. Minimum wages are an example of government controlled pricing.
‘Quantity demanded’ is how much consumers will purchase at a particular price. ‘Demand’ is the relation between quantity demanded and ALL possible prices. The definitions of ‘quantity supplied’ and Supply are similar; referring to the amount that firms are willing to sell. Quantity supplied can equal quantity demanded, but supply can never equal demand. This many sound like semantics, but it is the key to understanding how markets actually function.
In his op-ed piece, Professor Muirhead states that, under supply management, “domestic demand is matched with domestic supply”.  Disregarding the aforementioned error in terminology, equating quantity demanded and quantity supplied is exactly what the market mechanism does through changes in price. When government determines the maximum amount that can be produced, the market still determines the price. Thus, comparing the price of milk between supply management and market determined is not like comparing apples to oranges.  It’s comparing milk to milk.
The key element missing from the article is the side effect of supply management. To restrict the quantity produced, and thus increase price, governments issue quotas, or licenses to produce. Because the restricted supply raises the price of milk, more farmers would like to enter the dairy industry. They can’t, however, without obtaining a quota. If there is a demand for the quotas, and there is a limited supply, then the quotas themselves have value. Each time a Canadian buys milk or cheese they contribute to the profitability of these quotas. In a study done several years ago, the single largest cost of dairy producers was the acquisition of the quota.
Getting rid of supply management and compensating the existing producers for the value of their quotas would almost certainly reduce milk and cheese prices. With some notable exceptions, free markets are always more efficient than government intervention. Milk markets are not one of these exceptions.
Need more evidence? Ask the Venezuelans about toilet paper.


Thanks to my colleague JM for bringing this article to my attention.